The Law and Economics of Internet Access #
Innovation and Sec 230
- Develop and offer content without fear of legal liability
- “No provider or user of an interactive computer service shall be treated as the publisher or speaker of any information provided by another information content provider.”
- Innovation: want to make it likely that we’ll have access to more awesome content.
Net neutrality and Title II FCC public utility regulation
- Private carrier vs contract carrier vs common carrier
- Governments and ISPs should treat all data equally.
- Examples: blocking/filtering content, intentionally increasing or decreasing up/download speeds for certain users/content.
Common carrier designation
- June 2015 Federal Communications Commission ruling requires treating broadband providers as a telecom, and so a common carrier (like a public utility) under 1923 Communications Act.
- Was reversed by FCC vote under the new chairman, Ajit Pai, on December 14 2017
- This vote returned ISPs to oversight of the FTC
- This was upheld in Federal Court in 2018, but that decision also allowed states to pass their own Net Neutrality laws. 20+ Peurto Rico and DC have.
- These are being challenged by the US Dept. of Justice
Title II FCC common carrier designation
- The economic rationale; high fixed cost (initial investment to build out), low marginal cost (to serve each subsequent subscriber).
- Leads to monopoly power and calls for public utility style regulation.
- The “Bell Doctrine”
The Bell Doctrine
- Only the “edge” segment of delivery is subject to monopoly power, so heavily regulated there.
- Ma Bell: devices/equipment, long distance service (deregulated market); only local transmission was heavily regulated
- Electricity: plant generation, transmission lines (less regulated or deregulated); local distribution (heavily regulated)
- Broadband: devices/equipment, websites/apps (mostly unregulated); ISPs (FCC regulation)
Technology and Access Neutrality #
Net Neutrality
- Governments and ISPs should treat all data equally
- Examples: rules converning blocking/filtering content, intentionally increasing or decreasing up/download speeds for certain users/content, zero-rating.
Is FCC regulation necessary for access to awesome content?
- Case study: the internet of the 90s
- Early 90s bought access to content centers where they only got access to content, users and sites who were associated with the center (e.g. CompuServe or AOL)
- Why did that change?
ISP competition
- FTC had oversight of ISP abuses of market power from 2005-2015, policing anti-competitive practices.
- In most areas, there are at least two wireline competitors
- Plus, additional competition from wireless/5G.
- Market is at least a duopoly with the threat of new entry and innovation.
- A contestable enough market?
Does FCC regulation make it more likely that we’ll have a better access to awesome content?
- FCC is a media (content) regulator.
- FCC open internet rules expressly allowed ISPs to filter and block content.
- Effect of FCC regulations on build-out investment in areas currently underserved.
- Effect of regulations on other forms of competition: ICPs and the example of Netflix. Netflix opposed zero-rating in the US, but doesn’t in Australia (because they were newer in Australia it gives them a way to compete for users).
- Other regulator effects: who’s in a better position to thrive in a heavily regulated market? Large corporations/firms love a heavily regulated market.
Compliance costs and cronyism #
GRAHAM: So would you work with us in terms of what regulations you think are necessary in your industry?
ZUCKERBERG: Absolutely.
GRAHAM: Okay. Would you submit to us some proposed regulations?
ZUCKERBERG: Yes. And I’ll have my team follow up with you so, that way, we can have this discussion across the different categories where I think that this discussion needs to happen.
GRAHAM: Look forward to it.